May 18, 2024

The Decoy Effect: What It Is and How to Make It Work for You

Sellers in some cases use the decoy result to maximize the sales of a specific product or option.
Every retailer is interested in increasing their turnover or taking full advantage of the sales of a particular product at some time or other, and one method of doing this is by utilizing decoy products. A decoy product is an alternative that, when contributed to an option set, alters the relative attractiveness of the other options in the set and causes the customer to change their choice from one option to a more pricey or lucrative one. Its not planned to offer, just to nudge consumers towards a specific product by revealing them a somewhat worse alternative.
What is the decoy impact?
When people talk about the “decoy result,” they are referring to asymmetric decoys. These work by being “asymmetrically controlled.” This means the decoy is completely dominated by the target alternative, the product you would like the client to choose, in regards to viewed value, but only partially controlled by the other, “rival” product. This is why the decoy result is often called the “uneven dominance effect.” Its also called the “attraction impact” due to the fact that it causes a shift in choice from itself to a superior however comparable alternative.
Among the most well-known examples was explained by psychologist Dan Ariely, who noticed something odd about The Economist publications subscription options:

Now Beer As quality ranking is in the middle instead of the bottom of the set. In addition, the decoy has increased the series of the quality attribute from 20 (50 to 70) to 30 (40 to 70), making the 20-point benefit of Beer B over Beer An appear smaller. In Huber, Payne, and Putos research study, this resulted in a 20 percent increase in demand for Beer A.
There is also a special type of uneven decoy– the phantom decoy– which controls the target item but is not available at the time of option. These tend to work best when they are more appealing than the target on its finest dimension, and just as excellent on the other measurement. Using our beer example, ought to we desire to offer more of the superior craft beer, Beer B, we would use:.

When individuals talk about the “decoy result,” they are referring to asymmetric decoys. There is also a special type of asymmetric decoy– the phantom decoy– which controls the target product however is not available at the time of option. Decoys can be unfavorable to a specific segment of the population; for example, high-price/high-quality decoys tend to have a higher impact amongst individuals who desire and can afford such products, whereas low-price/low-quality decoy works better for those with limited monetary resources. The decoy ought to not be too inferior; decoys that are comparable yet very inferior to a target product are said to “taint” the comparable target product with their bad homes and produce a “repulsion result,” which leads customers to pick the rival item. Decoys that are perceived as popular tend to increase the decoy effect since individuals have a tendency to value the viewpoints of others.

Ariely, D. (2009 ). Naturally Irrational: The Hidden Forces That Shape Our Decisions. HarperCollins, New York, NY, USA.
Huber, J., Payne, J. W., & & Puto, C. (1982 ). Adding asymmetrically dominated alternatives: Violations of consistency and the similarity hypothesis. Journal of Consumer Research, 9( 1 ), 90-98. DOI: 10.1086/ 208899.
Scarpi, D., & & Pizzi, G. (2013 ). The effect of phantom decoys on understandings and choices. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 26( 5 ), 451-461. DOI: 10.1002/ bdm.1778.
Hedgcock, W., & & Rao, A. R. (2009 ). Trade-Off Aversion as an Explanation for the Attraction Effect: A Functional Magnetic Resonance Imaging Study. Journal of Marketing Research, 46( 1 ), 1-13. DOI: 10.1509% 2Fjmkr.46.1.1.
Simonson, I., & & Tversky, A. (1992 ). Choice in Context: Tradeoff Contrast and Extremeness Aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 29( 3 ), 281-295. DOI: 10.2307/ 3172740.
Bruce, G. S. Hardie, Johnson, E. J., & & Fader, P. S. (1993 ). Designing Loss Aversion and Reference Dependence Effects on Brand Choice. Marketing Science, 12( 4 ), 378-394. DOI: 10.1287/ mksc.12.4.378.
Context-dependent foraging decisions in rufous hummingbirds. DOI: 10.1098/ rspb.2003.2365.
Latty, T., & & Beekman, M. (2011 ). Irrational decision-making in an amoeboid organism: transitivity and context-dependent preferences. Procedures of the Royal Society of London B, 278: 307-312. DOI: 10.1098/ rspb.2010.1045.
Consumer Choice in Context: The Decoy Effect in Travel and Tourism. DOI: 10.1177/ 004728759503400106.
Benefiting from the Decoy Effect: A Case Study of the Online Diamond Marketplace. DOI: 10.1287/ mksc.2020.1231.
Slaughter, J. E., Sinar, E. F., & & Highhouse, S. (1999 ). Decoy impacts and attribute-level inferences. Journal of Applied Psychology, 84( 5 ), 823-828. DOI: 10.1037/ 0021-9010.84.5.823.
Real Estate Economics, American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 46( 4 ), 971-990. DOI: 10.1111/ 1540-6229.12176.
Herne, K. (1997 ). Decoy Alternatives in Policy Choices: Asymmetric Domination and Compromise Effects. European Journal of Political Economy, 13( 3 ), 575-89. DOI: 10.1016/ S0176-2680( 97 )00020-7.
Park, J., & & Kim, J. (2005 ). The effects of decoys on choice shifts: The role of appearance and supplying justification. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 15( 2 ), 94-107. DOI: 10.1207/ s15327663jcp1502_2.
Antecedents of the Attraction Effect: An Information-Processing Approach. DOI: 10.1177/ 002224379303000305.
The attraction effect is more noticable for consumers who rely on user-friendly thinking. DOI: 10.1007/ s11002-011-9157-y.
Liao, J., Zhang, Y., Li, Y., Li, H., Zilioli, S., & & Wu, Y. (2018 ). Exogenous Testosterone Increases Decoy Effect in Healthy Males. Frontiers in psychology, 9, 2188. DOI: 10.3389/ fpsyg.2018.02188.
Huber, J., Payne, J. W., & & Puto, C. P. (2014 ). Lets be Honest about the Attraction Effect. Journal of Marketing Research, 51( 4 ), 520-525. DOI: 10.1509/ jmr.14.0208.
The destination effect in choice making: Superior efficiency by older adults. DOI: 10.1080/ 02724980443000160.
Uneven decoy effects on lower-quality versus higher-quality brand names: Meta-analytic and speculative proof. Journal of Consumer Research, 22( 3 ), 268-284.
Removal by aspects: A theory of option. DOI: 10.1037/ h0032955.
Król, M., & & Król, M. (2019 ). Inability, not similarity of the decoy to target, is what drives the transfer of attention underlying the tourist attraction effect: Evidence from an eye-tracking research study with real options. Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics, 12( 2 ), 88-104. DOI: 10.1037/ npe0000104.
When the Good Looks Bad: An Experimental Exploration of the Repulsion Effect. DOI: 10.1177/ 0956797618779041.
Banerjee, P., Chatterjee, P., Masters, T., Mishra, S. (2020 ). Repulsion Effect: When an Asymmetrically Dominated Decoy Increases the Competitors Choice Share. Paper provided at the Seventeenth AIMS International Conference on Management.
Journal of Marketing Research, 51( 4 ), 487-507. DOI: 10.1509/ jmr.12.0061.
Ratneshwar, S., Shocker, A. D., & & Stewart, D. W. (1987 ). Toward comprehending the destination result: The implications of product stimulus meaningfulness and familiarity. Journal of Consumer Research, 13( 4 ), 520-533. DOI: 10.1086/ 209085.
Malkoc, S. A., Hedgcock, W., & & Hoeffler, S. (2013 ). In between a rock and a tough location: The failure of the attraction result among unappealing alternatives. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 23( 3 ), 317-329. DOI: 10.1016/ j.jcps.2012.10.008.
Pettibone, J. C. (2012 ). Evaluating the result of time pressure on uneven supremacy and compromise decoys in option. Judgment and Decision Making, 7( 4 ), 513-523.

Now that the most appealing choice is unavailable– possibly since its so popular– lots of consumers will feel obliged to get the next finest thing.
Phantom decoys can be divided into 2 sub-groups; those whose unavailability is known from the beginning (” known phantoms,” as in the example above), and those whose unavailability is revealed only after a client attempts to acquire them (” unknown phantoms”). Phantom decoys ought to be used with care. Whereas known phantoms normally exert a favorable effect, unknown phantoms tend to create stress and anger, and they can frighten customers away. Those who decide to select once again from the more restricted option set generally feel disappointed and unjustly treated, and they are less likely to buy from the merchant again. [3]
It might be the decoy result at work if one option appears much better than the others.
Why decoys work.
The decoy effect is thought about “an infraction of rationality.” A person is provided with 2 items and believes that Item A is much better than Item B, up until they exist with a third option and all of a sudden they choose that Item B is much better than Item A. That makes no sense. Why do decoys work?
Making choices between 2 products is a stressful service. [4] There are all those various characteristics to examine, values to bear in mind, mixes to think about, value to weigh. The decoy takes the stress away by highlighting which associates the client must focus on and making it simpler for them to validate the option of the controling alternative– the target– because it is so certainly much better than the dominated choice– the decoy. Having to validate ones option increases the decoy impact, as the focus of the choice is moved from a choice of good alternatives to an option of excellent reasons for choosing that alternative. [5]
Decoys are likewise stated to capitalize on loss hostility, a term that explains how our losses tend to be more undesirable than comparable gains are enjoyable. However the extremely meaning of “loss” is subjective; gains and losses are specified relative to some recommendation point. In a three-choice set, the decoy works as the reference point from which the customer compares downsides and benefits. From the perspective of the asymmetrically-dominated decoy, the target is better in every method, and the rival alternative is better in some ways but less excellent in others. Loss hostility causes the consumer to direct more focus towards disadvantages when making their choice, making them most likely to choose the target product.
Research study has likewise determined that people are more averse to lower quality than they are to higher costs, another psychological quality made use of by decoys that are developed to push customers toward targets of higher quality and greater price. [6] That stated, decoy impacts have been found in humming birds [7] and amoebas [8] We could simply be hard-wired to make options using comparative, context-dependent criteria.
10] 13]
Moreover, decoys have actually even been revealed to work when they remain in a different item domain and can not be straight compared to the target product. This is as long as consumers form a preliminary impression of each product independently before deciding, and items all differ along a common characteristic measurement. For example, in a choice set that includes a (target) fridge with a quick freezing time however moderately high operating expense and a (rival) fridge with a slow freezing time however low operating expense, a (decoy) dishwashing machine with a higher operating expense than both fridges and a synthetic intelligence function pushes the customer towards picking the target refrigerator. [14] Given that consumers typically encounter products successively instead of concurrently, and info about a products attributes is not constantly communicated in a manner that makes feature-by-feature comparisons simple, this type of decoy may be better than you believe.
To be truly effective, however, decoys need the ideal conditions.
When setting the sizes and prices for things like coffee, soft beverages, and popcorn, the decoy effect is frequently used.
The right consumers.
The decoy impact works best on people who are unfamiliar with the item. [15] For instance, its reasonable to choose a restaurant with a 5-star score over one with a 4-star score, and to choose paying $200 rather than $250 for supper. For the decoy result to happen, an individual requires to be uncertain whether a 1-star distinction in ratings is worth the $50 rate distinction. Individuals most prone to decoys are those who tend to depend on user-friendly thinking. [16] These people often will be guys. [17]
Decoys are not as effective when people are more thinking about the option at hand, perhaps since they are buying a big-ticket product; they pay more attention to the information thats readily available and are prepared to make the effort to process it more precisely. This is not the like searching for factors to validate a choice, due to the fact that an option best supported by reasons is not always the like the most ideal option. A consumer who typically never shops might select the very same brand of pasta sauce as their partner because this option is more quickly explained to the spouse, but it doesnt indicate they really believe that its an excellent trade-off between rate and quality.
Decoys are much less likely to work when a customer has strong prior preferences– for circumstances, they always focus on quality over cost, or they are faithful to a specific brand name. [18] When it comes to affecting people over the age of 65, decoys are practically absolutely ineffective. This is either since the experience that they have actually built up throughout the years in the market has actually made them much better able to overlook decoys, or because they are just more careful in their purchases. [19]
Decoys can be unfavorable to a particular segment of the population; for example, high-price/high-quality decoys tend to have a greater effect among individuals who prefer and can manage such items, whereas low-price/low-quality decoy works much better for those with minimal financial resources. [20] The best position.
For a decoy to be efficient, it should be placed correctly. When a decoy is really comparable to the target product but not clearly inferior, it can reduce the choice for the target through a “similarity effect,” a term that explains the truth that the intro of a new, comparable product tends to hurt similar options more than dissimilar ones. [21]
On the other hand, when the decoys inability is obvious, it increases the appearance of a similar target by drawing the consumers attention toward the qualities on which the target transcends. [22] The decoy must not be too inferior; decoys that are similar yet very inferior to a target item are said to “taint” the similar target item with their bad properties and produce a “repulsion impact,” which leads customers to select the rival product. [23] For example, if you are selling two TVs, one of which (the competitor) is of high quality but also costly, and the other of which (the target) is cheaper but of lower quality, a decoy which is also inexpensive and of much worse quality might trigger customers to believe “You get what you pay for” and make them choose quality over cost.
Decoys with skewed attributes should also be prevented. When two products are ranked as exceptional on one of two qualities and mediocre on the other– for example, MP3 gamer A, ranked 10/10 on functions but 4/10 on ease of usage, versus MP3 player B, ranked 9/10 on features however 5/10 on ease of usage– the addition of a decoy with qualities preferring player A– MP3 player C, ranked 10/10 on functions but 2/10 on ease of usage, likewise results in a repulsion impact. Since contrast of the exceptional qualities is basically meaningless, the consumer focuses on the second quality, resulting in the decoy being dropped and the target and rival products being organized together to form a category based on their viewed similarity.
The ideal info.
For the decoy to work, the supremacy relationship between it and the target product requires to be obvious. The decoy result tends to work best with products or services for which precise characteristic worths are generally explained, such as item rate, product functions, or length of service warranty. Decoys that include photos– for instance, in a different way priced hotel spaces whose quality is depicted with an image– typically do not work.
Decoys work much better when the details offered is not particularly significant. For example, if a customer has a choice in between 2 types of frozen concentrated orange juice and they are comparing the cost with quality ratings offered by a customer report, a basic decoy listing those 2 qualities will do the job. However, if they are offered more elaborate– that is, significant– information about the alternatives, for example, they are informed more about the flavor, scent, and nutritional values of the juices, this may prompt the customer to think of their own experiences and rely less on the details offered. This significantly decreases the decoy result. [26]
When attributes are expressed as losses, the decoy result is likewise seriously limited. Framing a returns policy as “Returns denied after 15 days” rather than “Returns permitted within 15 days” can be enough to get rid of the decoy result. [27] When people are required to pick in between unfavorable choices, their attention is drawn to the fact that they are being required to make compromises with no method of preventing a bad outcome. They end up being more watchful; even if the decoy at first points toward the asymmetrically controling target, they soon realize that the target is likewise undesirable and start evaluating the staying options.
Decoys that are perceived as popular tend to increase the decoy effect because individuals have a tendency to value the opinions of others. If the decoy is of a popular brand, consumers are more most likely to take it into consideration instead of dismissing it out of hand and to compare it to the nearest– target– brand.
Lastly, decoy results are driven by forces that make two-product contrasts work; in bigger choice sets (4, 5, 6, and so on), it becomes more tough for clients to keep track of which characteristics of which products are better than others. They are likewise ineffective when the consumer is not able to identify the supremacy relationship rapidly and unambiguously, for example, because the decoy and target products have been positioned too far apart on the client or a menu remains in a rush. It takes some time for customers to discover the relationships between the dominated decoy, the target product, and the competitor. [28] Consumers cant act on a relationship that they do not view.
References:.

Now, there is a compromise between cost and quality, and each of your customers picks according to which attribute they find most crucial.
You would like to sell more of Beer A, so you include a third choice, the decoy:.

Beer A, which costs $1.80 and has a quality ranking of 50.
Beer B, which costs $2.60 and has a quality score of 70.

Beer D, which costs $2.60 and has a quality ranking of 80 however is “out of stock”.

He wondered why the magazine would provide a print-only alternative for the exact same rate as a print-and-internet one, so he asked 100 of his trainees to choose one of the 3 choices; 16 chose the internet-only subscription and the other 84, the print-and-internet choice. This time, 68 of them chose the cheaper internet-only choice and 32, the print-and-internet alternative. The print-only decoy had made 52 individuals purchase the most expensive alternative and netted a hypothetical revenue of $3,432.
When choosing in between several choices of services or products, understanding the decoy impact could assist you make much better choices.
Their results were advanced because they challenged the established thinking that presenting a new item might only take market share away from an existing one.
They found that decoys were most effective when they extended the targets weakest measurement, making its deficit in that measurement seem lesser. State you are selling beer. You have two various beers on offer:.

an internet-only subscription for $59.
a print-and-internet subscription for $125.
a print-only subscription for $125.

Beer C, which costs $1.80 and has a quality score of 40.